What exactly
happened in the economic crisis in the late 1990’s and the financial crisis of
2007? What is the role of the U.S. government and The Federal Reserve in
containing these crises? How should we understand financial markets? Although
all of these are quite broad and undoubtedly tough questions, John Cassidy
manages to come to grips with them all in his recent book, How Markets Fail. Cassidy presents a thorough overview of “utopian”
economic theories, primarily based on Adam Smith’s precepts, then translates
and applies them in plain English to the recent economic crises. First
providing a basis of the knowledge that influenced Alan Greenspan, Ben
Bernanke, and other influential players, he untangles the web of problems that
created the bubbles, evaluates behaviors, and proposes uncomplicated solutions.
Overall, How Markets Fail is an
excellent book for readers of all backgrounds and all levels of expertise; it
is incredibly simple, given its comprehensiveness, and it imparts a wealth of
useful knowledge at all stages.
Cassidy begins his book by outlining
various components and aspects of “utopian economics.” Although his definition
is somewhat vague, the term generally refers to the belief—notably held by Alan
Greenspan—that markets are perfectly self-regulating, and that they naturally
achieve an optimum state without government intervention. The book chronicles
the development of pro-free market thought, and notes the major contributions
of several individuals, such as Friedrich Hayek, John Stuart Mill, and Milton
Friedman. Of course, there is also significant discussion of Adam Smith, whose
concept of the “invisible hand” led many to believe that all markets are best left to their own devices (Cassidy 31, 36). Cassidy
then moves to later work in this field, discussing price signaling, natural
resource allocation, and a general support of a “hands-off” philosophy (Cassidy
42-43, 50). While Smith was actually skeptical of unregulated financial
markets, over time, his views morphed into the false belief that markets are
perfectly efficient and balanced when left untouched. Although Cassidy fails to
explain how this happened, he makes a key point about which many, including
Greenspan, were mistaken. It is clear that the “invisible hand” is undeniable,
but a bit more discussion of the balance of free market and “planning” forces
would have cleared up ambiguities in Cassidy’s position and would have segued
nicely into his next points.
In the second and third sections of How Markets Fail, Cassidy
unapologetically brings this idealistic conception to earth. His practical
evaluation of the lead-up to recent financial crises is refreshing and
adeptly-argued, explaining things in simple terms of incentives, group
competition, and general psychology. Through this, Cassidy demonstrates the
need of some government regulation and ownership, citing intellectual property
protection and federal defense as some of the many beneficial and sensible examples
(Cassidy 133, 136). He then moves onto a discussion of “rational
irrationality,” or the confusing, self-interested behavior of financial players
in response to incentives. This mode of thinking is incredibly useful, and it
fits neatly within the overall depiction of the crisis. Essentially, there is
always an incentive for firms and analysts to choose the most desired
investments or stock (known as the “Keynes beauty pageant”), which leads to a
lack of diversification and increased risk in the case of failure (Cassidy 178).
Moreover, in a competitive market, there is an ever-present “prisoner’s
dilemma.” Though lending groups may begin conservative, lending only to
responsible businesses in order to ensure stability for all, there is always an
incentive for one to game the system and offer loans to slightly riskier
clients. Once this happens, bidding begins, and firms start pushing for more
precarious loans. Such a phenomenon was forecast almost prophetically by Hyman Minsky,
and was evidenced especially by the rapid expansion of adjustable rate subprime
loans (Cassidy 208, 258).
After
explaining the structural incentives driving this irresponsible behavior, Cassidy
tackles the bubbles themselves. In the beginning of the five stages—displacement,
boom, euphoria, peak, and bust—big lenders see high stock prices, rapidly
expanding financial markets, and a safety net of government backing. Firms such
as Citi Group, Goldman Sachs, and others, tried to “surf” the housing bubble,
extracting maximum profits and hoping to jump ship just in time. Banks took on
sizeable risks creating innumerable types of pooled capital, diversified risks,
and hybrid loans, knowing full well that taxpayers would foot the bill if the
projects failed (Cassidy 161, 184). While this was happening, the Fed continued
to believe that recent innovations had made the financial system “resilient,”
and that there was nothing to worry about (Cassidy 268). By contrasting this
vicious incentive system—which created self-destructive rational
irrationality—with the Fed’s hands-off approach, Cassidy makes it very clear
why the market failed. It was only after the government stepped in, bailed out
firms, socialized Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and realized the need for an
active Fed that things began to get better. In Cassidy’s view, only government
can counterbalance rational irrationality and create a framework of incentives
that would reward responsibility, measured risks, and a degree of financial conservatism
(Cassidy 329).
In
all, Cassidy’s take on market failure is quite thorough and logical, and there
are few areas in which any would say that it is lacking. His choice to begin
with the fundamentals of free market thought, and then progress to realistic
evaluation of human behavior in complex financial markets, creates a straightforward
explanation of a difficult topic. Moreover, Cassidy deftly cracks the
disillusioned belief in Smith’s almighty invisible hand, presenting an argument
for government intervention that would be received on both sides of the aisle. Still,
however, one might wonder if any of this counterbalancing or checking could be
done by the private sector—either by specifically-designated entities, or
perhaps by agreement of the most influential players in the financial system.
Similarly, though he is clearly a proponent of tempered government
intervention, Cassidy is a bit unclear on when the Fed and policymakers ought
to leave the market to its own devices. Of course, knee-jerk regulation may
create stability and stop “bubble-surfing,” but it could easily smother innovation
and de-incentivize growth. By delineating here between crisis and normal
business cycle, Cassidy might have drawn a clearer line and supplemented his
argument with intelligent discussion of a hotly-debated question.
While
his ending proposal for re-structuring and re-thinking is quite reasonable,
Cassidy unfortunately neglects one of the largest obstacles in monetary
policymaking: time lag. Presumably, a good portion of his recommendations would
be implemented as preemptive measures, and would already be in place when
crisis threatened again. Still, he fails to mention that even a more active Fed
would encounter difficulties, because it would take time for the economy to
react to its adjustments. Furthermore, Cassidy notes that the housing bubble was
unexpected, because Bernanke and others believed the economy to be immune to
such a thing. Given the comprehensive, multi-perspective approach of this book,
it would be quite interesting to see Cassidy’s projections about future crises.
Though he proposes a model to combat some of these rational irrationality
behaviors, there is likely still room for a new strain of financial busts. What
his book intends, however, it achieves remarkably well. How Markets Fail is not only a lesson in foundational economic
thought and mechanisms of crises, but also human behavior and group
mentality—lessons that apply in any era or policy system.
No comments:
Post a Comment